The Demopædia Encyclopedia on Population is under heavy modernization and maintenance. Outputs could look bizarre, sorry for the temporary inconvenience

Multilingual Demographic Dictionary, second unified edition, English volume

Difference between revisions of "90"

Multilingual Demographic Dictionary, second unified edition, English vol.
Jump to: navigation, search
(Etienne van de Walle et al., second 1982 edition *** existing text overwritten ***)
(Eugen Grebenik et al., first edition 1958)
Line 2: Line 2:
 
<!--'''90'''-->
 
<!--'''90'''-->
 
{{CurrentStatus}}
 
{{CurrentStatus}}
{{Unmodified edition II}}
+
{{Unmodified edition I}}
 
{{Summary}}
 
{{Summary}}
 
__NOTOC__
 
__NOTOC__
Line 9: Line 9:
 
=== 901 ===
 
=== 901 ===
  
A part of population theory ({{RefNumber|10|5|1}}) is concerned with the social and economic determinants and consequences of population trends. The theoretical treatment of population was largely centered in the past on the relation between total population and {{TextTerm|resources|1}}, i.e., the means available to maintain the population, or {{TextTerm|production|2}}, the creation of goods and services. More recently, the emphasis has shifted to the interrelations between ''population growth'' ({{RefNumber|70|1|1}}) and its components, and ''economic growth'' ({{RefNumber|90|3|1}}), particularly with respect to {{TextTerm|consumption|3}}, {{TextTerm|saving|4}} and {{TextTerm|investment|5}}.
+
The expression "population theory" (cf. {{RefNumber|10|1|.1}}) is used with widely differing meaning. In one restricted sense it refers to a systematic treatment of the logical and mathematical foundations of formal demography ({{RefNumber|10|2|.3}}). At the other extreme it is sometimes used for a purely speculative treatment of population questions. In the past, studies of interrelations between demographic and other phenomena have necessarily tended to be somewhat speculative. There is now an increased emphasis on more objective interdisciplinary studies dealing with specific relations between the results of demographic investigations and the results obtained by other kinds of scientific inquiry. The theoretical treatment of population was largely centred in the past on the relationship between total population and {{TextTerm|resources|1|901}}, i.e., the means available to maintain the population, or {{TextTerm|production|2|901}}, the creation of goods and services.
  
 
=== 902 ===
 
=== 902 ===
  
Consideration of the relations between population size and resources leads to the concepts of {{TextTerm|overpopulation|1}} and {{TextTerm|underpopulation|2}}. These terms are defined only at a given fixed {{TextTerm|level of development|3}}. When neither a larger nor a smaller population would yield advantages, there is said to be an {{TextTerm|optimum population|4}}, sometimes briefly called an {{TextTerm|optimum|4}}. The advantages yielded may be economic in character and in that case it is an {{TextTerm|economic optimum|5}}. The discussion of economic optima generally proceeds in terms of economic welfare but, as this is difficult to ascertain empirically, the {{TextTerm|level of living|6}} or {{TextTerm|standard of living|6}} is sometimes substituted. This is approximated by the {{TextTerm|real national income per capita|7}} i.e., the total amount of goods and services produced in a particular period (or its equivalent in money income adjusted for variation in purchasing power) divided by the total population during the period.
+
Consideration of the relation between population and resources leads to the concepts of {{TextTerm|over-population|1|902}} aud {{TextTerm|under-population|2|902}}. These terms are, of course, defined only at a given fixed {{TextTerm|level of development|3|902|OtherIndexEntry=development, level of}}. There is said to be over-population when the elimination of a number of inhabitants would yield certain advantages to the remainder. Under-population, on the other hand, implies that such advantages would accrue from a rise in numbers. When neither an increase nor a decrease would yield advantages, there is said to be an {{TextTerm|optimum population|4|902|OtherIndexEntry=population, optimum}}, sometimes briefly called an {{TextTerm|optimum|4|902|2}}. The advantages yielded may be economic in character and in that case it is an {{TextTerm|economic optimum|5|902|OtherIndexEntry=optimum, economic}}. The discussion of economic optima generally proceeds in terms of economic welfare but as this is difficult to ascertain empirically, the {{TextTerm|level of living|6|902|OtherIndexEntry=living, level of}} or {{TextTerm|standard of living|6|902|2|OtherIndexEntry=living, standard of}} is sometimes substituted. This is approximated by the {{TextTerm|real national income per head|7|902|OtherIndexEntry=income per head, real national}}, i.e., the total amount of goods and services produced in a particular period (or its equivalent in money income adjusted for variation in purchasing power) divided by the total population during the period.
{{Note|1| {{NoteTerm|Overpopulation}}, n. - '''{{NoteTerm|overpopulated}}, adj.'''}}
+
{{Note|5| Some writers have used the concept of a {{NoteTerm|power optimum}} and a {{NoteTerm|social optimum}} as well as of an {{NoteTerm|economic optimum}}.}}
{{Note|2| {{NoteTerm|Underpopulation}}, n. - '''{{NoteTerm|underpopulated}}, adj.'''}}
+
{{Note|6| The expression "standard of living" is restricted by some economists to mean an accepted goal or recognized set of needs, as contrasted with the level of living actually attained. Others use these terms interchangeably.}}
{{Note|5| Some writers have used the concept of a {{NoteTerm|power optimum}} and a {{NoteTerm|social optimum}} as well as of an economic optimum.}}
+
{{Note|7| The erroneous term {{NoteTerm|per capita}} is sometimes used.}}
{{Note|6| The expression "standard of living" is restricted by some economists to mean an accepted goal or recognized set of needs, as constrasted with the level of living actually attained. Others use these terms interchangeably. }}
 
{{Note|7| Other measures such as the {{NoteTerm|gross national product per capita}}, are also used. "Per capita", although grammatically incorrect, is used in place of the expression "per head".}}
 
  
 
=== 903 ===
 
=== 903 ===
  
Economists have emphasized the dynamic relations between {{TextTerm|economic growth|1}} or {{TextTerm|economic development|1}} and rates of population growth and changes in population structure; they are less interested today in the static concept of an optimum size, than in the dynamic concept of the {{TextTerm|optimum rate of growth|2}} of population, i.e., the rate of growth which will be consistent with the maximum rate of increase of the level of living. These relations are of particular concern in countries with a low level of living, which have come to be called {{TextTerm|less developed countries|3}} or {{TextTerm|developing countries|3}}.
+
Recently economists have emphasized the dynamic relations between {{TextTerm|economic growth|1|903|OtherIndexEntry=growth, economic}} or {{TextTerm|economic development|1|903|2|OtherIndexEntry=development, economic}} and rates of population growth and changes in population structure; they tend to use the concept of the {{TextTerm|optimum rate of change|2|903|OtherIndexEntry=change, optimum rate of}} of population, i. e., the rate of growth which will be consistent with the maximum rate of increase of the level of living. This problem is particularly acute in countries with a low level of living, which have come to be called {{TextTerm|under-developed|3|903}} countries, where the relationship between population growth and economic well-being has been the subject of investigation.
{{Note|3| Also: {{NoteTerm|underdeveloped countries}} or ''low-income countries.'' They are commonly contrasted with the {{NoteTerm|developed countries}}, or {{NoteTerm|more developed countries}}.}}
 
  
 
=== 904 ===
 
=== 904 ===
  
The {{TextTerm|maximum population|1}} of a territory, sometimes called its {{TextTerm|carrying capacity|1}}, is generally understood in an absolute sense to mean the largest number of persons that could be sustained under specified conditions; but is sometimes used to denote the largest number that could be supported at an assumed standard of living. Conversely, the {{TextTerm|minimum population|2}} is generally taken to be the smallest number of persons in an area which is consistent with {{TextTerm|group survival|3}}.
+
The {{TextTerm|maximum population|1|904|OtherIndexEntry=population, maximum}} of a territory, sometimes called its {{TextTerm|carrying capacity|1|904|2|OtherIndexEntry=capacity carrying}}, is generally understood in an absolute sense to mean the largest number of persons that could be sustained under specified conditions; but it is sometimes used to denote the largest number that could be supported at an assumed standard of living. Conversely the {{TextTerm|minimum population|2|904|OtherIndexEntry=population, minimum}} is generally taken to be the smallest number of persons in an area which is consistent with {{TextTerm|group survival|3|904|IndexEntry=group, survival|OtherIndexEntry=survival group}}.
  
 
=== 905 ===
 
=== 905 ===
  
The term {{TextTerm|population pressure|1}} is linked to concepts relating the size of the population and the ''resources'' ({{RefNumber|90|1|1}}) available. To say that this pressure is strong or weak in a certain area is to suggest that the population of the area is near or far from the maximum consistent with the resources which are available. According to {{TextTerm|Malthusian population theory|2}}, so called after its originator, Thomas Malthus, there will inevitably be pressure of population on the {{NoteTerm|means}} of {{TextTerm|subsistence|3}}. Any change in the volume of available means of subsistence would generate ''population growth'' ({{RefNumber|70|1|1}}) until {{TextTerm|population equilibrium|4}} would again be attained when the level of living had reached a {{TextTerm|subsistence level|5}}, i.e., a level just sufficient to maintain life. The equilibrium would be maintained by the elimination of any surplus population either through {{TextTerm|positive checks|6}}, sometimes known as {{TextTerm|Malthusian checks|6}} (famine, pestilence and war), or through the {{TextTerm|preventive check|7}} of {{TextTerm|moral restraint|8}} consisting of {{TextTerm|postponement of marriage|9}}, coupled with abstinence from sexual relations before marriage.
+
The term {{TextTerm|population pressure|1|905|OtherIndexEntry=pressure, population}} is used in a number of different senses. According to the {{TextTerm|Malthusian population theory|2|905|OtherIndexEntry=population theory, Malthusian}} ({{RefNumber|10|1|.4}}), so called after its originator, there will inevitably be pressure of population on the {{TextTerm|means of subsistence|3|905|OtherIndexEntry=subsistence, means of}}. Any change in the volume of available means of subsistence would generate population growth ({{RefNumber|70|1|.1}}) until {{TextTerm|population equilibrium|4|905|OtherIndexEntry=equilibrium, population}} would again be attained when the level of living had reached a {{TextTerm|subsistence level|5|905}}, i. e., a level just sufficient to maintain life. The equilibrium would be maintained by the elimination of any surplus population either through {{TextTerm|positive checks|6|905|IndexEntry=positive check|OtherIndexEntry=check, positive}}, sometimes known as {{TextTerm|Malthusian checks|6|905|2|IndexEntry=Malthusian check|OtherIndexEntry=check, Malthusian}} (famine, pestilence and war), or through the {{TextTerm|preventive check|7|905|OtherIndexEntry=check, preventive}} of {{TextTerm|moral restraint|8|905|OtherIndexEntry=restraint, moral}} consisting of {{TextTerm|postponement of marriage|9|905|OtherIndexEntry=marriage postponement}}, coupled with abstinence from sexual relations before marriage.
 
+
{{Note|7| The term {{NoteTerm|preventive check}} in English is generally used only with reference to the doctrines of Malthus.}}
6 and 7. The terms {{NoteTerm|positive check}} and {{NoteTerm|preventive check}} in English are generally used only with reference to the doctrines of Malthus.
 
  
 
=== 906 ===
 
=== 906 ===
  
Although the term {{TextTerm|Malthusianism|1}} originally refers to the theories of Malthus, it is often used today to denote the doctrine that a check in the rate of population growth is desirable. {{TextTerm|Neo-Malthusianism|2}}, whilst accepting the desirability of checking population growth, advocates that such restriction should be achieved through the use of ''birth control methods'' ({{RefNumber|62|7|3}}).
+
The term {{TextTerm|Malthusianism|1|906}} denotes the doctrine that a check in the rate of population growth is desirable. {{TextTerm|Neo-Malthusianism|2|906}}, whilst accepting the desirability of checking population growth, advocates that such restriction should be achieved through the use of birth control methods ({{RefNumber|62|4|.3}}).
{{Note|1| {{NoteTerm|Malthusianism}}, n. - {{NoteTerm|Malthusian}}, adj.: conforming to the doctrines of Malthus. The terms are sometimes used mistakenly to refer to the advocacy of family planning programs to solve economic problems.}}
+
{{Note|1| {{NoteTerm|Malthusianism}} n. {{NoteTerm|Malthusian}} n., one who accepts the doctrines of Malthus. The French term "malthusianisme" has acquired an extended meaning. It applies to any doctrine advocating a restriction in population growth, for whatever reason, and has even been used for economic restrictionism.}}
  
 
=== 907 ===
 
=== 907 ===
  
The process of transition from a situation in which both fertility and mortality were relatively high to one in which they are relatively low which has been observed in many countries, is called the demographic {{TextTerm|transition|1}} or {{TextTerm|population transition|1}}. In the process of moving from a {{TextTerm|pre-transitional stage|2}} to a {{TextTerm|post-transitional stage|3}}, there is typically a lag between the declines of mortality and fertility, so that a stage of {{TextTerm|transitional growth|4}} of population results. Economists have studied changes in {{TextTerm|productivity|5}}, i.e., production per member of the labor force, or per head of the population, associated with this transitional period.
+
The process of transition from a situation in which both fertility and mortality were relatively high to one in which they are relatively low which has been observed in many countries, is sometimes called the {{TextTerm|demographic revolution|1|907|OtherIndexEntry=revolution, demographic}} or {{TextTerm|vital revolution|1|907|2|OtherIndexEntry=revolution, vital}}. It has been suggested that the process of industrialization tends to bring about a type of demographic change which is characterized by a fall in mortality, followed after a period of time by a fall in fertility, thus resulting in rapid population growth during the period of {{TextTerm|demographic transition|2|907|OtherIndexEntry=transition, demographic}}. Economists have studied changes in {{TextTerm|productivity|3|907}}, i. e., in the production per member of the labour force, or per head of the population, associated with this transitional period.
{{Note|1| Sometimes called the {{NoteTerm|vital revolution}}. A further distinction is made between the {{NoteTerm|fertility transition}} and the {{NoteTerm|mortality transition}}. The {{NoteTerm|theory of the demographic transition}} associates historical changes in vital rates with socio-economic transformations attending the process of industrialization and urbanization. }}
 
  
 +
==<center><font size=12>* * * </font></center>==
 
{{SummaryShort}}
 
{{SummaryShort}}
  
 
{{OtherLanguages|90}}
 
{{OtherLanguages|90}}

Revision as of 20:40, 7 November 2009


Disclaimer : The sponsors of Demopaedia do not necessarily agree with all the definitions contained in this version of the Dictionary.

The harmonization of all the second editions of the Multilingual Demographic Dictionary is an ongoing process. Please consult the discussion area of this page for further comments.

This page is an excerpt of the first edition of the Multilingual Demographic Dictionary.
Please suppress this warning if you modify it.

Go to: Introduction to Demopædia | Instructions on use | Downloads
Chapters: Preface | 1. General concepts | 2. The treatment and processing of population statistics | 3. Distribution and classification of the population | 4. Mortality and morbidity | 5. Nuptiality | 6. Fertility | 7. Population growth and replacement | 8. Spatial mobility | 9. Economic and social aspects of demography
Pages: 10 | 11 | 12 | 13 | 14 | 15 | 16 | 20 | 21 | 22 | 23 | 30 | 31 | 32 | 33 | 34 | 35 | 40 | 41 | 42 | 43 | 50 | 51 | 52 | 60 | 61 | 62 | 63 | 70 | 71 | 72 | 73 | 80 | 81 | 90 | 91 | 92 | 93
Index: Global Index | Index of chapter 1 | Index of chapter 2 | Index of chapter 3 | Index of chapter 4 | Index of chapter 5 | Index of chapter 6 | Index of chapter 7 | Index of chapter 8 | Index of chapter 9


901

The expression "population theory" (cf. 101-.1) is used with widely differing meaning. In one restricted sense it refers to a systematic treatment of the logical and mathematical foundations of formal demography (102-.3). At the other extreme it is sometimes used for a purely speculative treatment of population questions. In the past, studies of interrelations between demographic and other phenomena have necessarily tended to be somewhat speculative. There is now an increased emphasis on more objective interdisciplinary studies dealing with specific relations between the results of demographic investigations and the results obtained by other kinds of scientific inquiry. The theoretical treatment of population was largely centred in the past on the relationship between total population and resources 1, i.e., the means available to maintain the population, or production 2, the creation of goods and services.

902

Consideration of the relation between population and resources leads to the concepts of over-population 1 aud under-population 2. These terms are, of course, defined only at a given fixed level of development 3. There is said to be over-population when the elimination of a number of inhabitants would yield certain advantages to the remainder. Under-population, on the other hand, implies that such advantages would accrue from a rise in numbers. When neither an increase nor a decrease would yield advantages, there is said to be an optimum population 4, sometimes briefly called an optimum 4. The advantages yielded may be economic in character and in that case it is an economic optimum 5. The discussion of economic optima generally proceeds in terms of economic welfare but as this is difficult to ascertain empirically, the level of living 6 or standard of living 6 is sometimes substituted. This is approximated by the real national income per head 7, i.e., the total amount of goods and services produced in a particular period (or its equivalent in money income adjusted for variation in purchasing power) divided by the total population during the period.

  • 5. Some writers have used the concept of a power optimum and a social optimum as well as of an economic optimum.
  • 6. The expression "standard of living" is restricted by some economists to mean an accepted goal or recognized set of needs, as contrasted with the level of living actually attained. Others use these terms interchangeably.
  • 7. The erroneous term per capita is sometimes used.

903

Recently economists have emphasized the dynamic relations between economic growth 1 or economic development 1 and rates of population growth and changes in population structure; they tend to use the concept of the optimum rate of change 2 of population, i. e., the rate of growth which will be consistent with the maximum rate of increase of the level of living. This problem is particularly acute in countries with a low level of living, which have come to be called under-developed 3 countries, where the relationship between population growth and economic well-being has been the subject of investigation.

904

The maximum population 1 of a territory, sometimes called its carrying capacity 1, is generally understood in an absolute sense to mean the largest number of persons that could be sustained under specified conditions; but it is sometimes used to denote the largest number that could be supported at an assumed standard of living. Conversely the minimum population 2 is generally taken to be the smallest number of persons in an area which is consistent with group survival 3.

905

The term population pressure 1 is used in a number of different senses. According to the Malthusian population theory 2 (101-.4), so called after its originator, there will inevitably be pressure of population on the means of subsistence 3. Any change in the volume of available means of subsistence would generate population growth (701-.1) until population equilibrium 4 would again be attained when the level of living had reached a subsistence level 5, i. e., a level just sufficient to maintain life. The equilibrium would be maintained by the elimination of any surplus population either through positive checks 6, sometimes known as Malthusian checks 6 (famine, pestilence and war), or through the preventive check 7 of moral restraint 8 consisting of postponement of marriage 9, coupled with abstinence from sexual relations before marriage.

  • 7. The term preventive check in English is generally used only with reference to the doctrines of Malthus.

906

The term Malthusianism 1 denotes the doctrine that a check in the rate of population growth is desirable. Neo-Malthusianism 2, whilst accepting the desirability of checking population growth, advocates that such restriction should be achieved through the use of birth control methods (624-.3).

  • 1. Malthusianism n. — Malthusian n., one who accepts the doctrines of Malthus. The French term "malthusianisme" has acquired an extended meaning. It applies to any doctrine advocating a restriction in population growth, for whatever reason, and has even been used for economic restrictionism.

907

The process of transition from a situation in which both fertility and mortality were relatively high to one in which they are relatively low which has been observed in many countries, is sometimes called the demographic revolution 1 or vital revolution 1. It has been suggested that the process of industrialization tends to bring about a type of demographic change which is characterized by a fall in mortality, followed after a period of time by a fall in fertility, thus resulting in rapid population growth during the period of demographic transition 2. Economists have studied changes in productivity 3, i. e., in the production per member of the labour force, or per head of the population, associated with this transitional period.

* * *

Go to: Introduction to Demopædia | Instructions on use | Downloads
Chapters: Preface | 1. General concepts | 2. The treatment and processing of population statistics | 3. Distribution and classification of the population | 4. Mortality and morbidity | 5. Nuptiality | 6. Fertility | 7. Population growth and replacement | 8. Spatial mobility | 9. Economic and social aspects of demography
Pages: 10 | 11 | 12 | 13 | 14 | 15 | 16 | 20 | 21 | 22 | 23 | 30 | 31 | 32 | 33 | 34 | 35 | 40 | 41 | 42 | 43 | 50 | 51 | 52 | 60 | 61 | 62 | 63 | 70 | 71 | 72 | 73 | 80 | 81 | 90 | 91 | 92 | 93
Index: Global Index | Index of chapter 1 | Index of chapter 2 | Index of chapter 3 | Index of chapter 4 | Index of chapter 5 | Index of chapter 6 | Index of chapter 7 | Index of chapter 8 | Index of chapter 9